EXPIRING TEMPORARY SAFEGUARDS ON APPAREL TRADE:
IMPLICATIONS FOR U.S. COTTON
Maria M. Mutuc
The 1995 Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC) provided for the calculated liberalization of the textiles and apparel sectors over a 10-year period except for some safeguard measures ending on December 31, 2008. These safeguard measures allowed for import restrictions by the
Trade in textiles and clothing has a long history of quantitative restrictions through the Multi-Fiber Arrangement (MFA). Under the MFA, developed textile importing countries negotiated bilateral agreements with developing exporting countries to set quotas on a country-specific basis. This contradicted the principles of nondiscrimination where all countries are treated equally with respect to trade measures and of reducing or avoiding absolute quantitative limits. The Uruguay Round of GATT negotiations resulted in the elimination of the MFA with the establishment of the WTO beginning in 1995. The Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC), which replaced the MFA, provided for the phased elimination of quotas within a transitional period of ten years, bringing the textiles and clothing sector back into the structure of the multilateral trading system.
Under the ATC, a minimum percentage of an importing country’s 1990 volume of textile and apparel imports was specified to be freed from quotas and hence “integrated” into the GATT-WTO disciplines in four phases: 16% on January 1, 1995, an additional 17% on January 1, 1998, another 18% on January 1, 2002, and the remaining 49% on January 1, 2005. Products not yet liberalized but subject to quotas or restrained in some manner had their quota growth rates increase by 16%, 25% and 27% in each phase, respectively. Although the ATC required importing countries to integrate articles from each of 4 categories: tops/yarns, fabrics, made-ups, and clothing , they were given the flexibility to select which articles to integrate at each phase as no allocation percentages were specified. Also, the universal set of product lines included not just items that were previously subject to the MFA but also articles that had never been restricted for some importing countries.
This allowed for developed importing countries to defer integration until January 1, 2005; 89% of apparel imports (most of which are high-value-added clothing items) and 47% of textile imports were left to be integrated in 2005 (USITC, 2004b) while those integrated in the first three stages were either not subject to MFA quotas or were subject to non-binding quotas or quotas not fully utilized by exporting countries.
To dampen a surge in imports and avoid a “hard landing” for domestic producers as a result of this “backloading”, the U.S. formed preferential and regional trading arrangements (PTAs/RTAs) concurrent and in response to the ATC. These PTAs accorded some advantage to member countries and diverted trade away from lower cost non-member countries, particularly in Asia and Once the safeguards expire and as the trading system moves to a completely free trade environment, U.S. producers will shift some of their assembly operations away from PTA countries or altogether source the garments from China and Asia where there is little use of U.S. fabrics in apparel production. With this shift of apparel production from protected and more developed countries to China and even to other previously constrained Asian countries with policies that favor domestic fiber producers and with significant cotton production, the net effect on the demand for U.S. cotton becomes an empirical question. While models that link the whole textiles and apparel sector to the cotton fiber sector exist (Mohanty and Pan, 2004; Diao and Somwaru, 2001; MacDonald et al, 2001; Elbehri, Thomas and Martin, 2003; Elbehri, 2004; MacDonald, Pan et al., 2004) in either a partial or general equilibrium setting, there is no extensive model of the cotton apparel sector that links to the cotton fiber sector for the U.S. This article develops a partial equilibrium framework that (a) vertically links the downstream cotton apparel sector to the upstream cotton sector; and (b) horizontally links the
See more of: Cotton Economics and Marketing Conference